Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model

The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, or Ramsey growth model, is a neoclassical model of economic growth based primarily on the work of Frank P. Ramsey,[1] with significant extensions by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans.[2][3] The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the Solow–Swan model in that the choice of consumption is explicitly microfounded at a point in time and so endogenizes the savings rate. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run steady state. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is Pareto optimal or Pareto efficient.[note 1]

Originally Ramsey set out the model as a social planner's problem of maximizing levels of consumption over successive generations.[4] Only later was a model adopted by Cass and Koopmans as a description of a decentralized dynamic economy with a representative agent. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model aims only at explaining long-run economic growth rather than business cycle fluctuations, and does not include any sources of disturbances like market imperfections, heterogeneity among households, or exogenous shocks. Subsequent researchers therefore extended the model, allowing for government-purchases shocks, variations in employment, and other sources of disturbances, which is known as real business cycle theory.

Mathematical description

Model setup

In the usual setup, time is continuous starting, for simplicity, at and continuing forever. By assumption, the only productive factors are capital and labour , both required to be nonnegative. The labour force, which makes up the entire population, is assumed to grow at a constant rate , i.e. , implying that with initial level at . Finally, let denote aggregate production, and denote aggregate consumption.

The variables that the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model ultimately aims to describe are , the per capita (or more accurately, per labour) consumption, as well as , the so-called capital intensity. It does so by first connecting capital accumulation, written in Newton's notation, with consumption , describing a consumption-investment trade-off. More specifically, since the existing capital stock decays by depreciation rate (assumed to be constant), it requires investment of current-period production output . Thus,

The relationship between the productive factors and aggregate output is described by the aggregate production function, . A common choice is the Cobb–Douglas production function , but generally any production function satisfying the Inada conditions is permissible. Importantly, though, is required to be homogeneous of degree 1, which economically implies constant returns to scale. With this assumption, we can re-express aggregate output in per capita terms For example, if we use the Cobb–Douglas production function with , then .

To obtain the first key equation of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, the dynamic equation for the capital stock needs to be expressed in per capita terms. Noting the quotient rule for , we have

a non-linear differential equation akin to the Solow–Swan model.

Maximizing welfare

If we ignore the problem of how consumption is distributed, then the rate of utility is a function of aggregate consumption. That is, . To avoid the problem of infinity, we exponentially discount future utility at a discount rate . A high reflects high impatience.

The social planner's problem is maximizing the social welfare function .

Assume that the economy is populated by identical immortal individuals with unchanging utility functions (a representative agent), such that the total utility is:The utility function is assumed to be strictly increasing (i.e., there is no bliss point) and concave in , with ,[note 2] where is marginal utility of consumption .

Thus we have the social planner's problem:

where an initial non-zero capital stock is given.

To ensure that the integral is well-defined, we impose .

Solution

The solution, usually found by using a Hamiltonian function,[note 3][note 4] is a differential equation that describes the optimal evolution of consumption,

the Keynes–Ramsey rule.[5]

The term , where is the marginal product of capital, reflects the marginal return on net investment, accounting for capital depreciation and time discounting.


Here is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, defined byIt is formally equivalent to the inverse of relative risk aversion. The quantity reflects the curvature of the utility function and indicates how much the representative agent wishes to smooth consumption over time. If the agent has high relative risk aversion, then it has low EIS, and thus would be more willing to smooth consumption over time.

It is often assumed that is strictly monotonically increasing and concave, thus . In particular, if utility is logarithmic, then it is constant:We can rewrite the Ramsey rule aswhere we interpret as the "consumption delay rate", because if it is high, then it means the agent is consuming a lot less now compared to later, which is essentially what delayed consumption is about.

Graphical analysis in phase space

Phase diagram of the Ramsey model, for the case of , and .
Phase space graph (or phase diagram) of the Ramsey model. The blue line represents the dynamic adjustment (or saddle) path of the economy in which all the constraints present in the model are satisfied. It is a stable path of the dynamic system. The red lines represent dynamic paths which are ruled out by the transversality condition.

The two coupled differential equations for and form the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans dynamical system.

A steady state for the system is found by setting and equal to zero. There are three solutions:

The first is the only solution in the interior of the upper quadrant. It is a saddle point (as shown below). The second is a repelling point. The third is a degenerate stable equilibrium.

By default, the first solution is meant, although the other two solutions are important to keep track of.

Any optimal trajectory must follow the dynamical system. However, since the variable is a control variable, at each capital intensity , to find its corresponding optimal trajectory, we still need to find its starting consumption rate . As it turns out, the optimal trajectory is the unique one that converges to the interior equilibrium point. Any other trajectory either converges to the all-saving equilibrium with , or diverges to , which means that the economy expends all its capital in finite time. Both achieve a lower overall utility than the trajectory towards the interior equilibrium point.

A qualitative statement about the stability of the solution requires a linearization by a first-order Taylor polynomial

where is the Jacobian matrix evaluated at steady state,[note 5] given by

which has determinant since , is positive by assumption, and since is concave (Inada condition). Since the determinant equals the product of the eigenvalues, the eigenvalues must be real and opposite in sign.[6]

Hence by the stable manifold theorem, the equilibrium is a saddle point and there exists a unique stable arm, or “saddle path”, that converges on the equilibrium, indicated by the blue curve in the phase diagram.

The system is called “saddle path stable” since all unstable trajectories are ruled out by the “no Ponzi scheme” condition:[7]

implying that the present value of the capital stock cannot be negative.[note 6]

History

Spear and Young re-examine the history of optimal growth during the 1950s and 1960s,[8] focusing in part on the veracity of the claimed simultaneous and independent development of Cass' "Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation" (published in 1965 in the Review of Economic Studies), and Tjalling Koopman's "On the concept of optimal economic growth" (published in Study Week on the Econometric Approach to Development Planning, 1965, Rome: Pontifical Academy of Science).

Over their lifetimes, neither Cass nor Koopmans ever suggested that their results characterizing optimal growth in the one-sector, continuous-time growth model were anything other than "simultaneous and independent". That the issue of priority ever became a discussion point was due only to the fact that in the published version of Koopmans' work, he cited the chapter from Cass' thesis that later became the RES paper. In his paper, Koopmans states in a footnote that Cass independently obtained conditions similar to what Koopmans finds, and that Cass also considers the limiting case where the discount rate goes to zero in his paper. For his part, Cass notes that "after the original version of this paper was completed, a very similar analysis by Koopmans came to our attention. We draw on his results in discussing the limiting case, where the effective social discount rate goes to zero". In the interview that Cass gave to Macroeconomic Dynamics, he credits Koopmans with pointing him to Frank Ramsey's previous work, claiming to have been embarrassed not to have known of it, but says nothing to dispel the basic claim that his work and Koopmans' were in fact independent.

Spear and Young dispute this history, based upon a previously overlooked working paper version of Koopmans' paper,[9] which was the basis for Koopmans' oft-cited presentation at a conference held by the Pontifical Academy of Sciences in October 1963.[10] In this Cowles Discussion paper, there is an error. Koopmans claims in his main result that the Euler equations are both necessary and sufficient to characterize optimal trajectories in the model because any solutions to the Euler equations which do not converge to the optimal steady-state would hit either a zero consumption or zero capital boundary in finite time. This error was apparently presented at the Vatican conference, although at the time of Koopmans' presenting it, no participant commented on the problem. This can be inferred because the discussion after each paper presentation at the Vatican conference is preserved verbatim in the conference volume.

In the Vatican volume discussion following the presentation of a paper by Edmond Malinvaud, the issue does arise because of Malinvaud's explicit inclusion of a so-called "transversality condition" (which Malinvaud calls Condition I) in his paper. At the end of the presentation, Koopmans asks Malinvaud whether it is not the case that Condition I simply guarantees that solutions to the Euler equations that do not converge to the optimal steady-state hit a boundary in finite time. Malinvaud replies that this is not the case, and suggests that Koopmans look at the example with log utility functions and Cobb-Douglas production functions.

At this point, Koopmans obviously recognizes he has a problem, but, based on a confusing appendix to a later version of the paper produced after the Vatican conference, he seems unable to decide how to deal with the issue raised by Malinvaud's Condition I.

From the Macroeconomic Dynamics interview with Cass, it is clear that Koopmans met with Cass' thesis advisor, Hirofumi Uzawa, at the winter meetings of the Econometric Society in January 1964, where Uzawa advised him that his student [Cass] had solved this problem already. Uzawa must have then provided Koopmans with the copy of Cass' thesis chapter, which he apparently sent along in the guise of the IMSSS Technical Report that Koopmans cited in the published version of his paper. The word "guise" is appropriate here, because the TR number listed in Koopmans' citation would have put the issue date of the report in the early 1950s, which it clearly was not.

In the published version of Koopmans' paper, he imposes a new Condition Alpha in addition to the Euler equations, stating that the only admissible trajectories among those satisfying the Euler equations is the one that converges to the optimal steady-state equilibrium of the model. This result is derived in Cass' paper via the imposition of a transversality condition that Cass deduced from relevant sections of a book by Lev Pontryagin.[11] Spear and Young conjecture that Koopmans took this route because he did not want to appear to be "borrowing" either Malinvaud's or Cass' transversality technology.

Based on this and other examination of Malinvaud's contributions in 1950s—specifically his intuition of the importance of the transversality condition—Spear and Young suggest that the neo-classical growth model might better be called the Ramsey–Malinvaud–Cass model than the established Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans honorific.

Notes

  1. ^ This result is due not just to the endogeneity of the saving rate but also because of the infinite nature of the planning horizon of the agents in the model; it does not hold in other models with endogenous saving rates but more complex intergenerational dynamics, for example, in Samuelson's or Diamond's overlapping generations models.
  2. ^ The assumption that is in fact crucial for the analysis. If , then for low values of the optimal value of is 0 and therefore if is sufficiently low there exists an initial time interval where even if , see Nævdal, E. (2019). "New Insights From The Canonical Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans Growth Model". Macroeconomic Dynamics. 25 (6): 1569–1577. doi:10.1017/S1365100519000786. S2CID 214268940.
  3. ^ The Hamiltonian for the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans problem is
    where is the costate variable usually economically interpreted as the shadow price. Because the terminal value of is free but may not be negative, a transversality condition similar to the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker “complementary slackness” condition is required. From the first-order conditions for maximization of the Hamiltonian one can derive the equation of motion for consumption, see Ferguson, Brian S.; Lim, G. C. (1998). Introduction to Dynamic Economic Models. Manchester University Press. pp. 174–175. ISBN 978-0-7190-4997-2, or Gandolfo, Giancarlo (1996). Economic Dynamics (3rd ed.). Berlin: Springer. pp. 381–384. ISBN 978-3-540-60988-9.
  4. ^ The problem can also be solved with classical calculus of variations methods, see Hadley, G.; Kemp, M. C. (1971). Variational Methods in Economics. New York: Elsevier. pp. 50–71. ISBN 978-0-444-10097-9.
  5. ^ The Jacobian matrix of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans system is
    See Afonso, Oscar; Vasconcelos, Paulo B. (2016). Computational Economics : A Concise Introduction. New York: Routledge. p. 163. ISBN 978-1-138-85965-4.
  6. ^ It can be shown that the “no Ponzi scheme” condition follows from the transversality condition on the Hamiltonian, see Barro, Robert J.; Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2004). Economic Growth (Second ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. pp. 91–92. ISBN 978-0-262-02553-9.

References

  1. ^ Ramsey, Frank P. (1928). "A Mathematical Theory of Saving". Economic Journal. 38 (152): 543–559. doi:10.2307/2224098. JSTOR 2224098.
  2. ^ Cass, David (1965). "Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation". Review of Economic Studies. 32 (3): 233–240. doi:10.2307/2295827. JSTOR 2295827.
  3. ^ Koopmans, T. C. (1965). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth". The Economic Approach to Development Planning. Chicago: Rand McNally. pp. 225–287.
  4. ^ Collard, David A. (2011). "Ramsey, saving and the generations". Generations of Economists. London: Routledge. pp. 256–273. ISBN 978-0-415-56541-7.
  5. ^ Blanchard, Olivier Jean; Fischer, Stanley (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp. 41–43. ISBN 978-0-262-02283-5.
  6. ^ Beavis, Brian; Dobbs, Ian (1990). Optimization and Stability Theory for Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. p. 157. ISBN 978-0-521-33605-5.
  7. ^ Roe, Terry L.; Smith, Rodney B. W.; Saracoglu, D. Sirin (2009). Multisector Growth Models: Theory and Application. New York: Springer. p. 48. ISBN 978-0-387-77358-2.
  8. ^ Spear, S. E.; Young, W. (2014). "Optimum Savings and Optimal Growth: The Cass–Malinvaud–Koopmans Nexus". Macroeconomic Dynamics. 18 (1): 215–243. doi:10.1017/S1365100513000291. S2CID 1340808.
  9. ^ Koopmans, Tjalling (December 1963). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth" (PDF). Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 163.
  10. ^ McKenzie, Lionel (2002). "Some Early Conferences on Growth Theory". In Bitros, George; Katsoulacos, Yannis (eds.). Essays in Economic Theory, Growth and Labor Markets. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 3–18. ISBN 978-1-84064-739-6.
  11. ^ Pontryagin, Lev; Boltyansky, Vladimir; Gamkrelidze, Revaz; Mishchenko, Evgenii (1962). The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes. New York: John Wiley.

Further reading

Read other articles:

Comic book series This article is about the Dark Horse comic book series. For the DC Comics character, see Mask (DC Comics). This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: The Mask comics – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (March 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message) Comics characte…

Jacqueline BlochBiographieNaissance 1967Nationalité françaiseFormation Université Pierre-et-Marie-Curie (doctorat) (jusqu'en 1994)École supérieure de physique et de chimie industrielles de la ville de Paris - PSLActivités Physicienne, chercheuseAutres informationsA travaillé pour Délégation Ile-de-France Sud (d) (depuis le 1er octobre 1994)Université d'Ottawa (depuis 1994)Centre national de la recherche scientifiqueMembre de Académie des sciences (2019)Distinctions Médaille d'argent …

この記事は検証可能な参考文献や出典が全く示されていないか、不十分です。出典を追加して記事の信頼性向上にご協力ください。(このテンプレートの使い方)出典検索?: コルク – ニュース · 書籍 · スカラー · CiNii · J-STAGE · NDL · dlib.jp · ジャパンサーチ · TWL(2017年4月) コルクを打ち抜いて作った瓶の栓 コルク(木栓、蘭&…

この記事は検証可能な参考文献や出典が全く示されていないか、不十分です。出典を追加して記事の信頼性向上にご協力ください。(このテンプレートの使い方)出典検索?: コルク – ニュース · 書籍 · スカラー · CiNii · J-STAGE · NDL · dlib.jp · ジャパンサーチ · TWL(2017年4月) コルクを打ち抜いて作った瓶の栓 コルク(木栓、蘭&…

American mathematician (born 1943) This article is about the American mathematician. For other people named Richard Hamilton, see Richard Hamilton. Richard HamiltonHamilton in 1982Born (1943-01-10) January 10, 1943 (age 81)Cincinnati, Ohio, United StatesNationalityAmericanAlma materYale University (BA)Princeton University (PhD)Known forConvergence theorems for Ricci flowDirichlet problem for harmonic maps and harmonic map heat flowEarle–Hamilton fixed-point theoremGage–Hamilto…

Halaman ini berisi artikel tentang album Super Junior. Untuk lagu, lihat Sexy, Free & Single (lagu). Sexy, Free & SingleAlbum studio karya Super JuniorDirilis04 Juli 2012 (2012-07-04)DirekamMei - Juni 2012 di SM Studios, Seoul, Korea SelatanGenreK-pop, R&B, electropop, dance, rap, EurohouseDurasi35:38BahasaKoreanLabelSM EntertainmentKMP HoldingsProduserLee Soo-manKronologi Super Junior Mr. Simple(2011)Mr. Simple2011 Sexy, Free & Single(2012) Hero (2013)Hero2013 Singel da…

American college football season Sports season1897 Western Conference football seasonSportFootballNumber of teams7ChampionWisconsinFootball seasons← 18961898 → 1897 Western Conference football standings vte Conf Overall Team W   L   T W   L   T Wisconsin $ 3 – 0 – 0 9 – 1 – 0 Chicago 3 – 1 – 0 11 – 1 – 0 Michigan 2 – 1 – 0 6 – 1 – 1 Illinois 1 – 1 – 0 6 – 2 – 0 Purdue…

Conglomerate company in Sri Lanka E. B. Creasy & Company PLCLogo of E. B. Creasy & CreasyCompany typePublicTraded asCSE: EBCR.N0000ISINLK0059N00002IndustryFMCGHealthcareFoodSteelEnergyFounded1878; 146 years ago (1878)FounderEdward Bennet CreasyHeadquartersColombo, Sri LankaKey peopleS. D. R. Arudpragasam (Chairman and Managing Director)R. Seevaratnam (Deputy Chairman)S. Rajaratnam (Joint Managing Director)Revenue LKR23,342 million (2023)Operating income LKR1,8…

此條目可参照英語維基百科相應條目来扩充。 (2021年5月6日)若您熟悉来源语言和主题,请协助参考外语维基百科扩充条目。请勿直接提交机械翻译,也不要翻译不可靠、低品质内容。依版权协议,译文需在编辑摘要注明来源,或于讨论页顶部标记{{Translated page}}标签。 约翰斯顿环礁Kalama Atoll 美國本土外小島嶼 Johnston Atoll 旗幟颂歌:《星條旗》The Star-Spangled Banner約翰斯頓環礁地…

  「俄亥俄」重定向至此。关于其他用法,请见「俄亥俄 (消歧义)」。 俄亥俄州 美國联邦州State of Ohio 州旗州徽綽號:七葉果之州地图中高亮部分为俄亥俄州坐标:38°27'N-41°58'N, 80°32'W-84°49'W国家 美國加入聯邦1803年3月1日,在1953年8月7日追溯頒定(第17个加入联邦)首府哥倫布(及最大城市)政府 • 州长(英语:List of Governors of {{{Name}}}]]) • …

Marxist school of thought Part of a series onMarxism Theoretical works Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844 The Condition of the Working Class in England The German Ideology The Communist Manifesto The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte Grundrisse Capital Critique of the Gotha Programme Dialectics of Nature The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State What Is to Be Done? The Accumulation of Capital Philosophical Notebooks Terrorism and Communism The State and Revolution E…

Reichsmark (Jerman) 2 ℛℳ,- Koin bergambar Paul von Hindenburg5 ℛℳ,- Uang kertas ISO 4217KodeDRM[butuh rujukan]DenominasiSubsatuan 1/100ReichspfennigBentuk jamakReichsmark ReichspfennigReichspfennigSimbolℛℳ ReichspfennigrpfUang kertas5 ℛℳ, 10 ℛℳ, 20 ℛℳ, 50 ℛℳ, 100 ℛℳ, 1000 ℛℳUang koin1 rpf, 2 rpf. 5 rpf, 10 rpf, 50 rpf, 1 ℛℳ, 2 ℛℳ, 5 ℛℳDemografiPengguna Republik Weimar Nazi Jerman Pemerintah FlensburgTemplat:Count…

Artikel atau sebagian dari artikel ini mungkin diterjemahkan dari Urdu alphabet di en.wikipedia.org. Isinya masih belum akurat, karena bagian yang diterjemahkan masih perlu diperhalus dan disempurnakan. Jika Anda menguasai bahasa aslinya, harap pertimbangkan untuk menelusuri referensinya dan menyempurnakan terjemahan ini. Anda juga dapat ikut bergotong royong pada ProyekWiki Perbaikan Terjemahan. (Pesan ini dapat dihapus jika terjemahan dirasa sudah cukup tepat. Lihat pula: panduan penerjemahan …

American knife maker (1933–2018) A. G. RussellBorn(1933-08-27)August 27, 1933Eudora, Arkansas, U.S.DiedOctober 12, 2018(2018-10-12) (aged 85)Occupation(s)Knifemaker, CEOSpouseGoldie RussellAwardsBlade Cutlery Hall of Fame A. G. Russell (August 27, 1933 – October 12, 2018)[1] was an American knife maker. He was born in Eudora, Arkansas where his great-grandfather taught him how to make knives when he was nine. Russell went on to make knives as a hobby and profession. In 1964,…

Italian oncologist and politician (1925–2016) Umberto VeronesiBorn(1925-11-28)28 November 1925Milan, Kingdom of ItalyDied8 November 2016(2016-11-08) (aged 90)Milan, ItalyNationalityItalianAlma materUniversity of MilanKnown forBreast-conserving surgery in breast cancer treatment with the invention of the technique of quadrantectomyScientific careerInstitutionsEuropean Institute of Oncology President of the Italian NuclearSafety AgencyIn office5 November 2010 – 3 Novemb…

Historic thoroughfare in the Marylebone district of London, England For the historic district in the Central West End neighborhood of St. Louis, Missouri, see Portland and Westmoreland Places. Portland PlacePortland Place wide streetNamesakeWilliam Cavendish-Bentinck, 3rd Duke of PortlandMaintained byTransport for LondonLocationLondon, United KingdomPostal codeW1Nearest Tube stationOxford CircusOtherKnown forBBC Broadcasting House Portland Place is a street in the Marylebone district of central …

Essays by American founding fathers opposed to the federal constitution Anti-Federalist Papers is the collective name given to the works written by the Founding Fathers who were opposed to, or concerned with, the merits of the United States Constitution of 1787. Starting on 25 September 1787 (eight days after the final draft of the US Constitution) and running through the early 1790s, these Anti-Federalists published a series of essays arguing against the ratification of the new Constitutio…

1973 single by Stevie WonderYou Are the Sunshine of My LifeSingle by Stevie Wonderfrom the album Talking Book B-sideTuesday HeartbreakReleasedMarch 1973Recorded1972Genre Pop-soul[1] easy listening[2] Length2:58LabelTamlaSongwriter(s)Stevie WonderProducer(s)Stevie WonderStevie Wonder singles chronology Superstition (1972) You Are the Sunshine of My Life (1973) Higher Ground (1973) Official audioYou Are The Sunshine Of My Life on YouTube You Are the Sunshine of My Life is a 1973 si…

US-based worldwide management consulting firm McKinsey redirects here. For other uses, see McKinsey (disambiguation). McKinsey & CompanyMcKinsey's New York office are in five floors of 3 World Trade CenterCompany typePrivateIndustryManagement consultingFounded1926; 98 years ago (1926)FounderJames O. McKinseyHeadquartersNew York City[1]Area servedWorldwideKey peopleBob Sternfels,Global Managing Partner[2]Revenue $15+ billion (2021)[3]Number of employe…

British ethnographer and colonial administrator (1851–1911) Herbert Hope Risley Sir Herbert Hope Risley KCIE CSI FRAI (4 January 1851 – 30 September 1911) was a British ethnographer and colonial administrator, a member of the Indian Civil Service who conducted extensive studies on the tribes and castes of the Bengal Presidency. He is notable for the formal application of the caste system to the entire Hindu population of British India in the 1901 census, of which he was in charg…